The Business Times

Why real wages in the US are still not rising

Published Thu, Jul 19, 2018 · 09:50 PM

THE United States labour market is closing in on full employment in an economic expansion that just began its 10th year, and yet the real hourly wage for the working class has been essentially flat for two years running. Why is that?

Economists ask this question every month when the government reports labour statistics. We repeatedly get solid job growth and lower unemployment, but not much to show for wages. Part of that has to do with inflation, productivity and remaining slack in the labour market.

But stagnant wages for factory workers and non-managers in the service sector - together they represent 82 per cent of the labour force - is mainly the outcome of a long power struggle that workers are losing. Even at a time of low unemployment, their bargaining power is feeble, the weakest that I have seen in decades. Hostile institutions - the Trump administration, the courts, the corporate sector - are limiting their avenues for demanding higher pay.

Looking at the historical relationship between working-class wages and unemployment, wage growth should be rising about a percentage point faster than it is right now. In June, the Bureau of Labor Statistics reports, wages were growing at a yearly rate of 2.7 per cent before inflation.

While wages have failed to accelerate, consumer prices have climbed. In 2015, inflation was close to zero. When price growth is zero, a dollar extra in your pay cheque means a dollar more real purchasing power. Real hourly pay grew at a healthy pace of about 2 per cent that year.

BACK TO NORMAL LEVELS

But price growth is back to more normal levels now. Over the past year, for example, consumer price inflation was 2.9 per cent, just about the same rate as hourly pay. Data released on Tuesday show that real weekly earnings for full-time, middle-wage workers have not grown at all since early 2017.

Barring an unforeseen shock to the system, I expect the jobless rate to continue to fall, probably to rates that we have not seen since the 1960s. The Federal Reserve forecasts unemployment of 3.5 per cent by the end of this year.

Unemployment at such a low level should force up wages, but it may not be enough to generate consistent, real gains.

That is because the trade war may push inflation higher, so it will take faster nominal wage growth to keep pace with prices. Thus far, the impact of the tariffs has been minimal, because of the small share of imports affected, and because "final products"- things that consumers buy versus intermediate materials used for production - have thus far been spared. But if US President Donald Trump follows through on his threat to place 10 per cent tariffs on US$200 billion of imports from China, including many consumer goods, prices could get a nudge.

Even before the trade war, the Federal Reserve was well into its campaign to raise the bench mark interest rate that it controls, and it has suggested that it may raise rates a bit more quickly than previously planned. Higher rates are intended to cool down the hot labour market, and this too could dampen the pace of wage growth.

Gross domestic product (GDP) has sped up, and may clock in at around 4 per cent in the second quarter of this year, but not enough of that growth is reaching workers. This is, of course, the defining characteristic of high inequality. Since the early 1980s, GDP growth has failed to consistently increase working-class incomes.

DEALING A BLOW

Still, in earlier periods, tight labour markets were able to deal a blow to inequality. The last time when unemployment was at 4 per cent in the latter 1990s, the share of national income going to pay cheques was three percentage points higher than it is today. In other words, even with the economy now near full employment, profits are squeezing pay cheques.

Slow productivity growth is another constraint on wages. When companies are able to produce more efficiently, they can absorb higher labour costs without sacrificing profit margins. But such gains have been elusive in this recovery, so businesses are increasing profits at labour's expense.

More than ever, the dynamics of this old-fashioned power struggle between labour and capital strongly favour corporations, employers and those whose income derives from stock portfolios rather than pay cheques.

This is evident in the large, permanent corporate tax cuts versus the small, temporary middle-class cuts that were passed at the end of last year. It is evident in the recent Supreme Court case that threatens the survival of the one unionised segment of labour - public workers - that still has some real clout.

It is evident in the increased concentration of companies and their unchecked ability to collude against workers, through anti-poaching and mandatory arbitration agreements that preclude worker-based class actions. And it is evident in a federal government that refuses to consider improved labour standards such as higher minimum wages and updated overtime rules.

Even if workers' real wages do pick up, their gains may be too short-lived to make a lasting difference. The next recession is lurking out there, and when it hits, whatever gains that American workers were able to wring out of the economic expansion will be lost to the long-term weakness of their bargaining clout. Workers' pay cheques reflect workers' power, and they are both much too weak. NYTIMES

BT is now on Telegram!

For daily updates on weekdays and specially selected content for the weekend. Subscribe to  t.me/BizTimes

Columns

SUPPORT SOUTH-EAST ASIA'S LEADING FINANCIAL DAILY

Get the latest coverage and full access to all BT premium content.

SUBSCRIBE NOW

Browse corporate subscription here